Via Feminist Law Profs, a piece of Digitized History (mislabeled “digital history,” which to me would be a history of online activities).
As FLP says, “Wow.”
Via Feminist Law Profs, a piece of Digitized History (mislabeled “digital history,” which to me would be a history of online activities).
As FLP says, “Wow.”
Greenwald, AT&T thanks the Blue Dog Democrats with a lavish party. Worth reading.
Le plus ça change, le plus c'est la même chose
I went down to my favorite furniture store, Woodworks, this weekend to get a couple extra shelves for one of the many, many bookcases I've bought from there over the years.
And I was chatting with one of the owners, or maybe he is the owner, I'm not sure, and I commented on the fact that the store seemed pretty busy despite the recession — I'd had to wait a while, while he wrote up the sale of a complicated, somewhat expensive, custom piece to an older couple. No, he said, business was down by a third over last year. And this is for a store that has good prices on decent quality stuff that tends to last.
A note to myself, but you're invited to listen in and comment if you'd like. [Update: comments glitch fixed.]
If I were teaching a first year legal “toolbox” course, I'd certainly teach Coase as part of it. And I'd include something like this too: Unenumerated: The Coase Theorem is false: contracts depend on tort law.
The proof that the Coase Theorem is false is actually quite simple: the assumptions of the Theorem contradict each other. The assumption that transactions are voluntary contradicts the assumption that any prior allocation of rights is possible, including rights that allow one party to coerce another. In fact, for the Theorem to at all make sense, a very large and crucial set of prior rights allocations must be excluded — namely any that allow any party to coerce another.
But we can't generally solve externalities problems by bargaining under this revised assumption. Externalities cannot be neatly distinguished from coercive acts, as extending one of Coase's own examples illustrates. In this example we have a railroad with a train that, passing by a farmer's wheat field, gives off sparks, which may start a fire in the field. In Coase's account, the prior allocation of rights might give the railroad the right to give off sparks, in which case the farmer must either plant his wheat far enough away from the railroad (wasting land) or buy the right to be free from sparks from the railroad. The prior allocation might instead already give the farmer the right to be completely free from sparks, in which case the railroad can either buy the right to emit sparks from the farmer or install spark-suppressors. If these are the two possible prior allocations of rights, Coase concluded that the railroad and the farmer will in the absence of transaction costs bargain to the most economically efficient outcome: if it costs less for the railroad to reduce the sparks than for the farmer to keep an unplanted firebreak, bargaining will achieve this outcome, and if the reverse, bargaining will achieve the reverse outcome, regardless of whether the farmer initially had the right to be free from sparks. So far, so good — it seems, on the surface, that if bargaining is costless an efficient outcome will be achieved.
The problem is that these are not the only prior allocations possible. The Coase Theorem is supposed to work under any other allocation of prior rights. But it doesn't. It fails for a large and crucially important class of prior allocations: namely any that allow one party to coerce another.
But I don't teach a first year “toolbox” course. Indeed, we don't have such a course. (We have “Elements” which — I'm told — is about how to read lines of cases, something which is important but different.)
I do, however, teach a Jurisprudence course of my own devising. I do “Of Coase and Cattle” there. Should I add something like this? It would be a distraction from where I'm trying to go, but maybe a useful one.
Then again, if I really let myself get distracted, I'd soon be trying to explain why the solution to the problem here is Habermassian, not libertarian. And that would take me very far from where the course is currently designed to go. But maybe I should bite the bullet and take it there? But that would make it much more of a philosophy course, and much less of an analytic jurisprudence course, than I intend it to be.
The Cardozo Law Review has a symposium volume, “Law and Event,” on the work of Alan Badiou.
I don't have time to read it.
Some pretty brutal stuff this week. And something subtle too. And then …. THE GAFFE ….
“You can be forgiven if you haven’t been following closely the fighting between Russia and Georgia over South Ossetia. But there are two lessons that we all absolutely must take away from these events:
1/ Under no circumstances should John McCain become president of the United States and you should do everything you can between now and November 4 to make sure that is the case.”)…
This was one of those “3 a.m. moments” that this election was supposedly all about (before McCain put oil drilling and Paris Hilton front and center). And McCain failed it. Disastrously. Worse than our worst fears. It is now apparent that McCain would be even more impulsively belligerent than Bush and even more arrogant and unwise in heeding the war-mongering urgings of his neocons advisors.
He also believes that if you put the internet in neutral, it'll stall.” — Mary Phillips-Sandy/Comedy Central
[W]hy not concentrate on character critiques that have some real grounding in reality? Just to give a few examples:
McCain is old and gets confused occasionally.
McCain is running an ugly, smear-based campaign.
McCain has a legendarily short fuse.
McCain is annoyingly self-righteous.
McCain's straight talk has evaporated in the face of his need to win evangelical votes.
Does this sound like commander-in-chief material? I think not. With solid repetition, these can all be made into fairly devastating attacks that have the added benefit of (a) being true, and (b) sounding true. So use them early and often.
The story about Mother Teresa “convincing” Mrs. McCain to bring home two children from an orphanage in Bangladesh has been retold many times. Initially, the “About Cindy McCain” page on the McCain campaign website read: “Mother Teresa convinced Cindy to take two babies in need of medical attention to the United States. One of those babies is now their adopted daughter, 16-year-old Bridget McCain.”
The media picked up the theme. A story earlier this year on ABC’s “Good Morning America” stated, “With Mother Teresa’s encouragement she brought her fourth child, Bridget, home.” An April 2008 Wall Street Journal profile states that Mother Teresa “implored” Cindy to bring the girls to the United States. Other articles say Cindy did it “at the behest” of Mother Teresa.
But a source who was with McCain on that 1991 trip, and who asked that his name not be used because of prior legal dealings with the McCain family, says that Mother Teresa was not at the orphanage when Cindy decided to bring the two girls home.
A 1991 article in the Arizona Star at the time of the adoption only mentions that the children were from an orphanage that was started by Mother Teresa. It does not mention a meeting with Mother Teresa or her asking McCain to bring the girls to the US.
According to biographies of Mother Teresa, in 1991 she was in Mexico where she developed medical problems. From there, she went to a hospital in La Jolla, Calif.
A McCain source acknowledged that Cindy McCain did not meet Mother Teresa during the 1991 trip to Bangladesh but said McCain did meet her later on, although the source could not say when or where. The campaign has since reworded the reference to the adoption on its website.
The story may be worse than it seems; the adoption was during a period when Ms. McCain was addicted to pain pills; her drug dependency might have mixed her up on details. But it appears that's not when the story got embellished — see Mark Nickolas, Huffpo, The Anatomy of a Deception: How The McCains Changed Their Baby Adoption Story Just Before 2008 Bid